Knowledge Business
A global community of knowledge-driven organizations dedicated to networking, benchmarking and sharing best practices leading to superior performance.
Click for English version Click for Japanese version
Log In To Member Area
Email the site administrator Email the site administrator
Feedback Click to send your feedback
Site Search: 
You are here
 >> 
Read Knowledge Library
Companies Expanding Abroad: Knowledge Seekers vs. Conquerors    [Date Added : 03/22/2004 ]
In 2002, General Electric moved a major research and development lab for its medical systems division from Japan to China. The move seemed motivated by the usual enticements - lower costs and lower barriers, both formal and informal, to doing business in the world's most populous country.

However, Wharton management professor Wilbur Chung interprets GE's decision differently. Chung, who studies corporate decisions to expand abroad, believes that GE's move is an attempt to tap into China's unique wellspring of knowledge. What strikes him is GE's assertion that the lab would design products tailored to emerging economies such as China's.

"Whatever China develops is rolled out to other developing countries," Chung says. "China may have a lower GDP per capita than developed countries, but the Chinese have a strong sense of how products should be designed for their market."

Chung and Juan Alcacer, a management professor at New York University, believe that many companies go abroad with the same mindset that GE took to China. That is, they are pilgrims - knowledge seekers as Chung and Alcacer call them - not conquerors. "Firms may expand abroad in search of capabilities that are not available in their home markets," according to Chang.

Traditional strategic thinking views companies going abroad mainly to find cheaper inputs or profitable markets. Two famous examples are BMW and Mercedes-Benz. During the 1990s, BMW built a big car plant in Spartanburg County, SC, USA, while Mercedes constructed one in Vance, Alabama. Both German automakers publicly announced their intentions and thus started bidding wars among several US states vying for the investments. In the end, Alabama offered more than US $250 million worth of inducements to Mercedes, while South Carolina gave about US $130 million to BMW.

Chung and Alcacer have investigated which are the most knowledge-seeking industries, and what are the characteristics of markets that attract knowledge-seekers.

They have examined 1,784 foreign corporate investments into the United States from 1987 to 1993. They looked at both acquisitions and so-called greenfield deals (blank-slate investments where a company comes in, buys land, erects a building and starts operations). Then they repeated their analysis using 170 economic areas defined by the US Commerce Department's Bureau of Economic Analysis, which allowed them to analyze big cities within states as well as multi-state metro areas such as Greater New York, or Washington, DC and its suburbs in Maryland and Virginia.

To determine whether an area had a lode of knowledge that foreign firms could mine, they counted the number of engineers and scientists in each, the number of patents each area generated and the amount of money spent locally on research and development.

Not surprisingly, they found that knowledge seeking is most prevalent among foreign companies in R&D-heavy industries such as pharmaceuticals, semiconductors and electronics. In fact, they found that drug makers are twice as likely to seek knowledge abroad as companies in any other industry.

Where were knowledge seekers most likely to invest? Many investments, 32% of the sample, fall into four major US metropolitan areas: New York City, San Francisco, Los Angeles and Chicago. In contrast, a region of the United States known mostly for agriculture - the Dakotas and Idaho - had no investments during the period of investigation.

An objection to Chung and Alcacer's research - and to the notion of knowledge seeking via foreign expansion, in general - might be that investing abroad is a costly way to learn. After all, patents and technical manuals are widely published, and newly graduated scientists and engineers are eager for jobs.

But Chung argues that this objection misconstrues the nature of knowledge. "Knowledge can be broken into a codifiable piece - the stuff you can write down - and a tacit piece," he explains. "It's things you can break down vs. things that are intuitive. It's like riding a bike. You can explain to someone the mechanics of it, but that's not the same as doing it."

What do Chung and Alcacer's findings mean for managers? "Managers should enhance existing safeguards that protect proprietary knowledge," they note. In other words, managers might want to think carefully before entering into joint ventures with companies that are expanding into their markets from elsewhere. They should at least make sure they have legal agreements to prevent their new partners from making off with their companies' technologies or employees.

"You need to think about clear complementary gains," Chung says. "You need to be getting something from them, and they need to be getting something from you."

What about policymakers? What should they make of Chung and Alcacer's arguments? Traditionally, investments from foreign firms have been celebrated by holding press conferences and ribbon-cutting ceremonies, as South Carolina and Alabama did when they landed BMW and Mercedes. But if Chung is right, these investments may not always be victories.

"If many foreign firms enter seeking new knowledge, productivity gains may not accrue, and a nation's technological uniqueness might be more quickly replicated," he and Alcacer point out. Of course, investments from foreign firms may still bring benefits such as more jobs and spin-off economic activity as, for example, suppliers spring up near the foreign firm's new plant.

Even so, Chung and Alcacer's analysis suggests that the 'elephant-hunt' strategy of corporate recruiting - i.e., focusing effort and money on landing blockbuster deals like BMW and Mercedes as opposed to encouraging local development - may be wrong, at least for areas that are technology leaders. In effect, a region may be paying an outside company to come in and take knowledge from its homegrown firms.

(Extracted from an article appearing in 'Knowledge@Wharton,' March10-23, 2004. Copyright 2004. Wharton School of Business, University of Pennsylvania)
Go to top
Conditions of Use & Sale     Site Contents